THE
ASCENT OF MONEY: A FINANCIAL HISTORY OF THE WORLD
BY
NIALL FERGUSON
2.
OF HUMAN BONDAGE
Early in
Bill Clinton’s first hundred days as president, his campaign manager James
Carville made a remark that has since become famous. ‘I used to think if there
was reincarnation, I wanted to come back as the president or the pope or a .400
baseball hitter,’ he told the Wall Street Journal. ‘But now I want
to come back as the bond market. You can intimidate everybody.’ Rather to his
surprise, bond prices had risen in the wake of the previous November’s
election, a movement that had actually preceded a speech by the president in
which he pledged to reduce the federal deficit. ‘That investment market,
they’re a tough crowd,’ observed Treasury Secretary Lloyd Bentsen. ‘Is this a
credible effort [by the president]? Is the administration going to hang in
there pushing it? They have so judged it.’ If bond prices continued to rally,
said Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan, it would be ‘by far the most
potent [economic] stimulus that I can imagine.’1 What
could make public officials talk with such reverence, even awe, about a mere
market for the buying and selling of government IOUs?
After the
creation of credit by banks, the birth of the bond was the second great
revolution in the ascent of money. Governments (and large corporations) issue
bonds as a way of borrowing money from a broader range of people and
institutions than just banks. Take the example of a Japanese government
ten-year bond with a face value of 100,000 yen and a fixed interest rate or
‘coupon’ of 1.5 per cent - a tiny part of the vast 838 trillion yen mountain of
public debt that Japan has accumulated, mostly since the 1980s. The bond
embodies a promise by the Japanese government to pay 1.5 per cent of 100,000
yen every year for the next ten years to whoever owns the bond. The initial
purchaser of the bond has the right to sell it whenever he likes at whatever
price the market sets. At the time of writing, that price is around 102,333
yen. Why? Because the mighty bond market says so.
From
modest beginnings in the city-states of northern Italy some eight hundred years
ago, the market for bonds has grown to a vast size. The total value of
internationally traded bonds today is around $18 trillion. The value of bonds
traded domestically (such as Japanese bonds owned by Japanese investors) is a
staggering $50 trillion. All of us, whether we like it or not (and most of us
do not even know it), are affected by the bond market in two important ways.
First, a large part of the money we put aside for our old age ends up being
invested in the bond market. Secondly, because of its huge size, and because
big governments are regarded as the most reliable of borrowers, it is the bond
market that sets long-term interest rates for the economy as a whole. When bond
prices fall, interest rates soar, with painful consequences for all borrowers.
The way it works is this. Someone has 100,000 yen they wish to save. Buying a
100,000 yen bond keeps the capital sum safe while also providing regular
payments to the saver. To be precise, the bond pays a fixed rate or ‘coupon’ of
1.5 per cent: 1,500 yen a year in the case of a 100,000 yen bond. But the marketinterest
rate or current yield is calculated by dividing the coupon by the market price,
which is currently 102,333 yen: 1,500 ÷ 102,333 = 1.47 per cent.k Now
imagine a scenario in which the bond market took fright at the huge size of the
Japanese government’s debt. Suppose investors began to worry that Japan might
be unable to meet the annual payments to which it had committed itself. Or
suppose they began to worry about the health of the Japanese currency, the yen,
in which bonds are denominated and in which the interest is paid. In such
circumstances, the price of the bond would drop as nervous investors sold off
their holdings. Buyers would only be found at a price low enough to compensate
them for the increased risk of a Japanese default or currency depreciation. Let
us imagine the price of our bond fell to 80,000. Then the yield would be 1,500
÷ 80,000 = 1.88 per cent. At a stroke, long-term interest rates for the
Japanese economy as a whole would have jumped by just over two fifths of one
per cent, from 1.47 per cent to 1.88. People who had invested in bonds for
their retirement before the market move would be 22 per cent worse off, since
their capital would have declined by as much as the bond price. And people who
wanted to take out a mortgage after the market move would find themselves
paying at least 0.41 per cent a year (in market parlance, 41 basis points)
more. In the words of Bill Gross, who runs the world’s largest bond fund at the
Pacific Investment Management Company (PIMCO), ‘bond markets have power because
they’re the fundamental base for all markets. The cost of credit, the interest
rate [on a benchmark bond], ultimately determines the value of stocks, homes,
all asset classes.’
From a
politician’s point of view, the bond market is powerful partly because it
passes a daily judgement on the credibility of every government’s fiscal and
monetary policies. But its real power lies in its ability to punish a
government with higher borrowing costs. Even an upward move of half a
percentage point can hurt a government that is running a deficit, adding higher
debt service to its already high expenditures. As in so many financial
relationships, there is a feedback loop. The higher interest payments make the
deficit even larger. The bond market raises its eyebrows even higher. The bonds
sell off again. The interest rates go up again. And so on. Sooner or later the
government faces three stark alternatives. Does it default on a part of its
debt, fulfilling the bond market’s worst fears? Or, to reassure the bond
market, does it cut expenditures in some other area, upsetting voters or vested
interests? Or does it try to reduce the deficit by raising taxes? The bond
market began by facilitating government borrowing. In a crisis, however, it can
end up dictating government policy.
So how
did this ‘Mr Bond’ become so much more powerful than the Mr Bond created by Ian
Fleming? Why, indeed, do both kinds of bond have a licence to kill?
MOUNTAINS
OF DEBT
‘War’,
declared the ancient Greek philosopher Heraclitus, ‘is the father of all
things.’ It was certainly the father of the bond market. In Pieter van der
Heyden’s extraordinary engraving, The Battle about Money, piggy
banks, money bags, barrels of coins, and treasure chests - most of them heavily
armed with swords, knives and lances - attack each other in a chaotic
free-for-all. The Dutch verses below the engraving say: ‘It’s all for money and
goods, this fighting and quarrelling.’ But what the inscription could equally
well have said is: ‘This fighting is possible only if you can raise the money
to pay for it.’ The ability to finance war through a market for government debt
was, like so much else in financial history, an invention of the Italian
Renaissance.
For much
of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, the medieval city-states of Tuscany
- Florence, Pisa and Siena - were at war with each other or with other Italian
towns. This was war waged as much by money as by men. Rather than require their
own citizens to do the dirty work of fighting, each city hired military
contractors (condottieri) who raised armies to annex land and loot
treasure from its rivals. Among the condottieri of the 1360s
and 1370s one stood head and shoulders above the others. His commanding figure
can still be seen on the walls of Florence’s Duomo - a painting originally
commissioned by a grateful Florentine public as a tribute to his ‘incomparable
leadership’. Unlikely though it may seem, this master mercenary was an Essex
boy born and raised in Sible Hedingham. So skilfully did Sir John Hawkwood wage
war on their behalf that the Italians called him Giovanni Acuto,
John the Acute. The Castello di Montecchio outside Florence was one of many
pieces of real estate the Florentines gave him as a reward for his services. Yet
Hawkwood was a mercenary, who was willing to fight for anyone who would pay
him, including Milan, Padua, Pisa or the pope. Dazzling frescos in Florence’s
Palazzo Vecchio show the armies of Pisa and Florence clashing in 1364, at a
time when Hawkwood was fighting for Pisa. Fifteen years later, however, he had
switched to serve Florence, and spent the rest of his military career in that
city’s employ. Why? Because Florence was where the money was.
The cost
of incessant war had plunged Italy’s city-states into crisis. Expenditures even
in years of peace were running at double tax revenues. To pay the likes of
Hawkwood, Florence was drowning in deficits. You can still see in the records
of the Tuscan State Archives how the city’s debt burden increased a hundred-fold
from 50,000 florins at the beginning of the fourteenth century to 5 million by
1427.2 It was literally a mountain of debt - hence its
name: the monte commune or communal debt mountain.3 By
the early fifteenth century, borrowed money accounted for nearly 70 per cent of
the city’s revenue. The ‘mountain’ was equivalent to more than half the
Florentine economy’s annual output.
From whom
could the Florentines possibly have borrowed such a huge sum? The answer is
from themselves. Instead of paying a property tax, wealthier citizens were
effectively obliged to lend money to their own city government. In return for
these forced loans (prestanze), they received interest. Technically,
this was not usury (which, as we have seen, was banned by the Church) since the
loans were obligatory; interest payments could therefore be reconciled with
canon law as compensation (damnum emergens) for the real or putative
costs arising from a compulsory investment. As Hostiensis (or Henry) of Susa
put it in around 1270:
If some merchant, who is accustomed to pursue
trade and the commerce of fairs, and there profit from, has, out of charity to
me, who needs it badly, lent money with which he would have done business, I
remain obliged to his interesse [note
this early use of the term ‘interest’] . . .4
A crucial
feature of the Florentine system was that such loans could be sold to other
citizens if an investor needed ready money; in other words, they were
relatively liquid assets, even though the bonds at this time were no more than
a few lines in a leather-bound ledger.
In
effect, then, Florence turned its citizens into its biggest investors. By the
early fourteenth century, two thirds of households had contributed in this way
to financing the public debt, though the bulk of subscriptions were accounted
for by a few thousand wealthy individuals.5 The Medici
entries in the ‘Ruolo delle prestanze’ testify not only to the scale of their
wealth at this time, but also to the extent of their contributions to the
city-state’s coffers. One reason that this system worked so well was that they
and a few other wealthy families also controlled the city’s government and
hence its finances. This oligarchical power structure gave the bond market a
firm political foundation. Unlike an unaccountable hereditary monarch, who
might arbitrarily renege on his promises to pay his creditors, the people who
issued the bonds in Florence were in large measure the same people who bought
them. Not surprisingly, they therefore had a strong interest in seeing that
their interest was paid.
Nevertheless,
there was a limit to how many more or less unproductive wars could be waged in
this way. The larger the debts of the Italian cities became, the more bonds
they had to issue; and the more bonds they issued, the greater the risk that
they might default on their commitments. Venice had in fact developed a system
of public debt even earlier than Florence, in the late twelfth century.
The monte vecchio(Old Mountain) as the consolidated debt was known,
played a key role in funding Venice’s fourteenth-century wars with Genoa and
other rivals. A new mountain of debt arose after the protracted war with the
Turks that raged between 1463 and 1479: the monte nuovo.6 Investors
received annual interest of 5 per cent, paid twice yearly from the city’s
various excise taxes (which were levied on articles of consumption like salt).
Like the Florentine prestanze, the Venetian prestiti were
forced loans, but with a secondary market which allowed investors to sell their
bonds to other investors for cash.7 In the late
fifteenth century, however, a series of Venetian military reverses greatly
weakened the market for prestiti. Having stood at 80 (20 per cent
below their face value) in 1497, the bonds of the Venetian monte nuovo were
worth just 52 by 1500, recovering to 75 by the end of 1502 and then collapsing
from 102 to 40 in 1509. At their low points in the years 1509 to 1529, monte
vecchio sold at just 3 and monte nuovo at 10.8
Now, if
you buy a government bond while war is raging you are obviously taking a risk,
the risk that the state in question may not pay your interest. On the other
hand, remember that the interest is paid on the face value of
the bond, so if you can buy a 5 per cent bond at just 10 per cent of its face
value you can earn a handsome yield of 50 per cent. In essence, you expect a
return proportional to the risk you are prepared to take. At the same time, as
we have seen, it is the bond market that sets interest rates for the economy as
a whole. If the state has to pay 50 per cent, then even reliable commercial
borrowers are likely to pay some kind of war premium. It is no coincidence that
the year 1499, when Venice was fighting both on land in Lombardy and at sea
against the Ottoman Empire, saw a severe financial crisis as bonds crashed in
value and interest rates soared.9Likewise, the bond market
rout of 1509 was a direct result of the defeat of the Venetian armies at
Agnadello. The result in each case was the same: business ground to a halt.
It was
not only the Italian city-states that contributed to the rise of the bond
market. In Northern Europe, too, urban polities grappled with the problem of
financing their deficits without falling foul of the Church. Here a somewhat
different solution was arrived at. Though they prohibited the charging of
interest on a loan (mutuum), the usury laws did not apply to the
medieval contract known as the census, which allowed one party to
buy a stream of annual payments from another. In the thirteenth century, such
annuities started to be issued by northern French towns like Douai and Calais
and Flemish towns like Ghent. They took one of two forms: rentes
heritables or erfelijkrenten, perpetual revenue streams
which the purchaser could bequeath to his heirs, or rentes viagères or lijfrenten,
which ended with the purchaser’s death. The seller, but not the buyer, had the
right to redeem the rente by repaying the principal. By the
mid sixteenth century, the sale of annuities was raising roughly 7 per cent of
the revenues of the province of Holland.10
Both the
French and Spanish crowns sought to raise money in the same way, but they had
to use towns as intermediaries. In the French case, funds were raised on behalf
of the monarch by the Paris hôtel de ville; in the Spanish case,
royal juros had to be marketed through Genoa’s Casa di San
Giorgio (a private syndicate that purchased the right to collect the city’s
taxes) and Antwerp’s beurs, a forerunner of the modern stock
market. Yet investors in royal debt had to be wary. Whereas towns, with their
oligarchical forms of rule and locally held debts, had incentives not to
default, the same was not true of absolute rulers. As we saw in Chapter 1, the
Spanish crown became a serial defaulter in the late sixteenth and seventeenth
centuries, wholly or partially suspending payments to creditors in 1557, 1560,
1575, 1596, 1607, 1627, 1647, 1652 and 1662.11
Part of
the reason for Spain’s financial difficulties was the extreme costliness of
trying and failing to bring to heel the rebellious provinces of the northern
Netherlands, whose revolt against Spanish rule was a watershed in financial as
well as political history. With their republican institutions, the United
Provinces combined the advantages of the city-state with the scale of a
nation-state. They were able to finance their wars by developing Amsterdam as
the market for a whole range of new securities: not only life and perpetual
annuities, but also lottery loans (whereby investors bought a small probability
of a large return). By 1650 there were more than 65,000 Dutch rentiers,
men who had invested their capital in one or other of these debt instruments
and thereby helped finance the long Dutch struggle to preserve their
independence. As the Dutch progressed from self-defence to imperial expansion,
their debt mountain grew high indeed, from 50 million guilders in 1632 to 250
million in 1752. Yet the yield on Dutch bonds declined steadily, to a low of
just 2.5 per cent in 1747 - a sign not only that capital was abundant in the
United Provinces, but also that investors had little fear of an outright Dutch
default.12
With the
Glorious Revolution of 1688, which ousted the Catholic James II from the
English throne in favour of the Dutch Protestant Prince of Orange, these and
other innovations crossed the English Channel from Amsterdam to London. The
English fiscal system was already significantly different from that of the
continental monarchies. The lands owned by the crown had been sold off earlier
than elsewhere, increasing the power of parliaments to control royal
expenditure at a time when their powers were waning in Spain, France and the
German lands. There was already an observable move in the direction of a
professional civil service, reliant on salaries rather than peculation. The
Glorious Revolution accentuated this divergence. From now on there would be no
more regular defaulting (the ‘Stop of Exchequer’ of 1672, when, with the crown
deep in debt, Charles II had suspended payment of his bills, was still fresh in
the memories of London investors). There would be no more debasement of the
coinage, particularly after the adoption of the gold standard in 1717. There
would be parliamentary scrutiny of royal finances. And there would be a
sustained effort to consolidate the various debts that the Stuart dynasty had
incurred over the years, a process that culminated in 1749 with the creation by
Sir Henry Pelham of the Consolidated Fundl.13 This
was the very opposite of the financial direction taken in France, where
defaults continued to happen regularly; offices were sold to raise money rather
than to staff the civil service; tax collection was privatized or farmed out;
budgets were rare and scarcely intelligible; the Estates General (the nearest
thing to a French parliament) had ceased to meet; and successive controllers-general
struggled to raise money by issuing rentes and tontines(annuities
sold on the lives of groups of people) on terms that were excessively generous
to investors.14 In London by the mid eighteenth century
there was a thriving bond market, in which government consols were the dominant
securities traded, bonds that were highly liquid - in other words easy to sell
- and attractive to foreign (especially Dutch) investors.15 In
Paris, by contrast, there was no such thing. It was a financial divergence that
would prove to have profound political consequences.
Since it
was arguably the most successful bond ever issued, it is worth pausing to look
more closely at the famed British consol. By the late eighteenth century it was
possible to invest in two types: those bearing a 3 per cent coupon, and those
bearing a 5 per cent coupon. They were otherwise identical, in that they were
perpetual bonds, without a fixed maturity date, which could be bought back
(redeemed) by the government only if their market price equalled or exceeded
their face value (par). The illustration opposite shows a typical consol, a
partially printed, partially handwritten receipt, stating the amount invested,
the face value of the security, the investor’s name and the date:
Received this 22 Day of January 1796 of Mrs.
Anna Hawes the Sum of One hundred and one pounds being the Consideration for
One hundred pounds Interest or Share in the Capital or Joint Stock of Five per
Cent Annuities, consolidated July 6th, 1785 . . . transferable at the Bank of
England . . .
Given
that she paid £101 for a £100 consol, Mrs Hawes was securing an annual yield on
her investment of 4.95 per cent. This was not an especially well-timed
investment. April that year saw the first victory at Montenotte of a French
army led by a young Corsican commander named Napoleon Bonaparte. He won again
at Lodi in May. For the next two decades, this man would pose a greater threat
to the security and financial stability of the British Empire, not to mention
the peace of Europe, than all the Habsburgs and Bourbons put together.
Defeating him would lead to the rise of yet another mountain of debt. And as
the mountain rose, so the price of individual consols declined - by as much as
30 per cent at the lowest point in Britain’s fortunes.
The
meteoric rise of a diminutive Corsican to be Emperor of France and master of
the European continent was an event few could have predicted in 1796, least of
all Mrs Anna Hawes. Yet an even more remarkable (and more enduring) feat of
social mobility was to happen in almost exactly the same timeframe. Within just
a few years of Napoleon’s final defeat at Waterloo, a man who had grown up amid
the gloom of the Frankfurt ghetto had emerged as a financial Bonaparte: the
master of the bond market and, some ventured to suggest, the master of European
politics as well. That man’s name was Nathan Rothschild.
THE
BONAPARTE OF FINANCE
Master of
unbounded wealth, he boasts that he is the arbiter of peace and war, and that
the credit of nations depends upon his nod; his correspondents are innumerable;
his couriers outrun those of sovereign princes, and absolute sovereigns;
ministers of state are in his pay. Paramount in the cabinets of continental
Europe, he aspires to the domination of our own.16
Those
words were spoken in 1828 by the Radical MP Thomas Dunscombe. The man he was
referring to was Nathan Mayer Rothschild, founder of the London branch of what
was, for most of the nineteenth century, the biggest bank in the world.17 It
was the bond market that made the Rothschild family rich - rich enough to build
forty-one stately homes all over Europe, among them Waddesdon Manor in
Buckinghamshire, which has been restored in all its gilded glory by the 4th
Lord Rothschild, Nathan’s great-great-great-grandson. His illustrious forebear,
according to Lord Rothschild, was ‘short, fat, obsessive, extremely clever,
wholly focused . . . I can’t imagine he would have been a very pleasant person
to have dealings with.’ His cousin Evelyn de Rothschild takes a similar view.
‘I think he was very ambitious,’ he says, contemplating Nathan Rothschild’s
portrait in the boardroom at the offices of N. M. Rothschild in London’s St
Swithin’s Lane, ‘and I think he was very determined. I don’t think he suffered
fools lightly.’
Though the
Rothschilds were compulsive correspondents, relatively few of Nathan’s letters
to his brothers have survived. There is one page, however, that clearly conveys
the kind of man he was. Written, like all their letters, in almost
indecipherable Judendeutsch (German transliterated into Hebrew
characters), it epitomizes what might be called his Jewish work ethic and his
impatience with his less mercurial brothers:
I am writing to you giving my opinion, as it is
my damned duty to write to you . . . I am reading through your letters not just
once but maybe a hundred times. You can well imagine that yourself. After
dinner I usually have nothing to do. I do not read books, I do not play cards,
I do not go to the theatre, my only pleasure is my business and in this way I
read Amschel’s, Salomon’s, James’s and Carl’s letters . . . As far as Carl’s
letter [about buying a bigger house in Frankfurt] is concerned . . . all this
is a lot of nonsense because as long as we have good business and are rich
everybody will flatter us and those who have no interest in obtaining revenues
through us begrudge us for it all. Our Salomon is too good and agreeable to
anything and anybody and if a parasite whispers something into his ear he
thinks that all human beings are noble minded[;] the truth is that all they are
after is their own interest.18
Small
wonder his brothers called Nathan ‘the general in chief’. ‘All you ever write’,
complained Salomon wearily in 1815, ‘is pay this, pay that, send this, send
that.’19 It was this phenomenal drive, allied to innate
financial genius, that propelled Nathan from the obscurity of the
Frankfurt Judengasse to mastery of the London bond market.
Once again, however, the opportunity for financial innovation was provided by
war.
On the
morning of 18 June 1815, 67,000 British, Dutch and German troops under the Duke
of Wellington’s command looked out across the fields of Waterloo, not far from
Brussels, towards an almost equal number of French troops commanded by the
French Emperor, Napoleon Bonaparte. The Battle of Waterloo was the culmination
of more than two decades of intermittent conflict between Britain and France.
But it was more than a battle between two armies. It was also a contest between
rival financial systems: one, the French, which under Napoleon had come to be
based on plunder (the taxation of the conquered); the other, the British, based
on debt.
Never had
so many bonds been issued to finance a military conflict. Between 1793 and 1815
the British national debt increased by a factor of three, to £745 million, more
than double the annual output of the UK economy. But this increase in the
supply of bonds had weighed heavily on the London market. Since February 1792,
the price of a typical £100 3 per cent consol had fallen from £96 to below £60
on the eve of Waterloo, at one time (in 1797) sinking below £50. These were
trying times for the likes of Mrs Anna Hawes.
According
to a long-standing legend, the Rothschild family owed the first millions of
their fortune to Nathan’s successful speculation about the effect of the
outcome of the battle on the price of British bonds. In some versions of the
story, Nathan witnessed the battle himself, risked a Channel storm to reach
London ahead of the official news of Wellington’s victory and, by buying bonds
ahead of a huge surge in prices, pocketed between £20 and £135 million. It was
a legend the Nazis later did their best to embroider. In 1940 Joseph Goebbels
approved the release of Die Rothschilds, which depicts an
oleaginous Nathan bribing a French general to ensure the Duke of Wellington’s
victory, and then deliberately misreporting the outcome in London in order to
precipitate panic selling of British bonds, which he then snaps up at
bargain-basement prices. Yet the reality was altogether different.20 Far
from making money from Wellington’s victory, the Rothschilds were very nearly
ruined by it. Their fortune was made not because of Waterloo, but despite it.
After a
series of miscued interventions, British troops had been fighting against Napoleon
on the Continent since August 1808, when the future Duke of Wellington, then
Lieutenant-General Sir Arthur Wellesley, led an expeditionary force to
Portugal, invaded by the French the previous year. For the better part of the
next six years, there would be a recurrent need to get men and matériel to
the Iberian Peninsula. Selling bonds to the public had certainly raised plenty
of cash for the British government, but banknotes were of little use on distant
battlefields. To provision the troops and pay Britain’s allies against France,
Wellington needed a currency that was universally acceptable. The challenge was
to transform the money raised on the bond market into gold coins, and to get
them to where they were needed. Sending gold guineas from London to Lisbon was
expensive and hazardous in time of war. But when the Portuguese merchants
declined to accept the bills of exchange that Wellington proffered, there
seemed little alternative but to ship cash.
The son
of a moderately successful Frankfurt antique dealer and bill broker, Nathan
Rothschild had arrived in England only in 1799 and had spent most of the next
ten years in the newly industrializing North of England, purchasing textiles
and shipping them back to Germany. He did not go into the banking business in
London until 1811. Why, then, did the British government turn to him in its
hour of financial need? The answer is that Nathan had acquired valuable
experience as a smuggler of gold to the Continent, in breach of the blockade
that Napoleon had imposed on trade between England and Europe. (Admittedly, it
was a breach the French authorities tended to wink at, in the simplistic
mercantilist belief that outflows of gold from England must tend to weaken the
British war effort.) In January 1814, the Chancellor of the Exchequer
authorized the Commissary-in-Chief, John Charles Herries, to ‘employ that
gentleman [Nathan] in the most secret and confidential manner to collect in
Germany, France and Holland the largest quantity of French gold and silver
coins, not exceeding in value £600,000, which he may be able to procure within
two months from the present time.’ These were then to be delivered to British
vessels at the Dutch port of Helvoetsluys and sent on to Wellington, who had by
now crossed the Pyrenees into France. It was an immense operation, which
depended on the brothers’ ability to tap their cross-Channel credit network and
to manage large-scale bullion transfers. They executed their commission so well
that Wellington was soon writing to express his gratitude for the ‘ample . . .
supplies of money’. As Herries put it: ‘Rothschild of this place has executed
the various services entrusted to him in this line admirably well, and though a
Jew [sic], we place a good deal of confidence in him.’ By May 1814 Nathan
had advanced nearly £1.2 million to the government, double the amount envisaged
in his original instructions.
Mobilizing
such vast amounts of gold even at the tail end of a war was risky, no doubt.
Yet from the Rothschilds’ point of view, the hefty commissions they were able
to charge more than justified the risks. What made them so well suited to the
task was that the brothers had a ready-made banking network within the family -
Nathan in London, Amschel in Frankfurt, James (the youngest) in Paris, Carl in
Amsterdam and Salomon roving wherever Nathan saw fit. Spread out around Europe,
the five Rothschilds were uniquely positioned to exploit price and exchange
rate differences between markets, the process known as arbitrage. If the price
of gold was higher in, say, Paris than in London, James in Paris would sell
gold for bills of exchange, then send these to London, where Nathan would use
them to buy a larger quantity of gold. The fact that their own transactions on
Herries’s behalf were big enough to affect such price differentials only added
to the profitability of the business. In addition, the Rothschilds also handled
some of the large subsidies paid to Britain’s continental allies. By June 1814,
Herries calculated that they had effected payments of this sort to a value of
12.6 million francs. ‘Mr Rothschild’, remarked the Prime Minister, Lord
Liverpool, had become ‘a very useful friend’. As he told the Foreign Secretary
Lord Castlereagh, ‘I do not know what we should have done without him . . .’.
By now his brothers had taken to calling Nathan the master of the Stock
Exchange.
After his
abdication in April 1814, Napoleon had been exiled to the small Italian island
of Elba, which he proceeded to rule as an empire in miniature. It was too small
to hold him. On 1 March 1815, to the consternation of the monarchs and
ministers gathered to restore the old European order at the Congress of Vienna,
he returned to France, determined to revive his Empire. Veterans of the grande
armée rallied to his standard. Nathan Rothschild responded to this
‘unpleasant news’ by immediately resuming gold purchases, buying up all the
bullion and coins he and his brothers could lay their hands on, and making it
available to Herries for shipment to Wellington. In all, the Rothschilds
provided gold coins worth more than £2 million - enough to fill 884 boxes and
fifty-five casks. At the same time, Nathan offered to take care of a fresh
round of subsidies to Britain’s continental allies, bringing the total of his
transactions with Herries in 1815 to just under £9.8 million. With commissions
on all this business ranging from 2 to 6 per cent, Napoleon’s return promised
to make the Rothschilds rich men. Yet there was a risk that Nathan had
underestimated. In furiously buying up such a huge quantity of gold, he had
assumed that, as with all Napoleon’s wars, this would be a long one. It was a
near fatal miscalculation.
Wellington
famously called the Battle of Waterloo ‘the nearest run thing you ever saw in
your life’. After a day of brutal charges, countercharges and heroic defence,
the belated arrival of the Prussian army finally proved decisive. For
Wellington, it was a glorious victory. Not so for the Rothschilds. No doubt it
was gratifying for Nathan Rothschild to receive the news of Napoleon’s defeat
first, thanks to the speed of his couriers, nearly forty-eight hours before
Major Henry Percy delivered Wellington’s official despatch to the Cabinet. No
matter how early it reached him, however, the news was anything but good from
Nathan’s point of view. He had expected nothing as decisive so soon. Now he and
his brothers were sitting on top of a pile of cash that nobody needed - to pay
for a war that was over. With the coming of peace, the great armies that had
fought Napoleon could be disbanded, the coalition of allies dissolved. That
meant no more soldiers’ wages and no more subsidies to Britain’s wartime
allies. The price of gold, which had soared during the war, would be bound to
fall. Nathan was faced not with the immense profits of legend but with heavy
and growing losses.
But there
was one possible way out: the Rothschilds could use their gold to make a
massive and hugely risky bet on the bond market. On 20 July 1815 the evening
edition of the London Courier reported that Nathan had made ‘great
purchases of stock’, meaning British government bonds. Nathan’s gamble was that
the British victory at Waterloo, and the prospect of a reduction in government
borrowing, would send the price of British bonds soaring upwards. Nathan bought
more and, as the price of consols duly began to rise, he kept on buying.
Despite his brothers’ desperate entreaties to realize profits, Nathan held his
nerve for another year. Eventually, in late 1817, with bond prices up more than
40 per cent, he sold. Allowing for the effects on the purchasing power of
sterling of inflation and economic growth, his profits were worth around £600
million today. It was one of the most audacious trades in financial history,
one which snatched financial victory from the jaws of Napoleon’s military
defeat. The resemblance between victor and vanquished was not lost on
contemporaries. In the words of one of the partners at Barings, the
Rothschilds’ great rivals, ‘I must candidly confess that I have not the nerve
for his operations. They are generally well planned, with great cleverness and
adroitness in execution - but he is in money and funds what Bonaparte was in
war.’21 To the Austrian Chancellor Prince Metternich’s
secretary, the Rothschilds were simply die Finanzbonaparten.22 Others
went still further, though not without a hint of irony. ‘Money is the god of
our time,’ declared the German poet Heinrich Heine in March 1841, ‘and
Rothschild is his prophet.’23
To an
extent that even today remains astonishing, the Rothschilds went on to dominate
international finance in the half century after Waterloo. So extraordinary did
this achievement seem to contemporaries that they often sought to explain it in
mystical terms. According to one account dating from the 1830s, the Rothschilds
owed their fortune to the possession of a mysterious ‘Hebrew talisman’ that
enabled Nathan Rothschild, the founder of the London house, to become ‘the
leviathan of the money markets of Europe’.24 Similar
stories were being told in the Pale of Settlement, to which Russian Jews were
confined, as late as the 1890s.25 As we have seen, the
Nazis preferred to attribute the rise of the Rothschilds to the manipulation of
stock market news and other sharp practice. Such myths are current even today.
According to Song Hongbing’s best-selling book Currency Wars,
published in China in 2007, the Rothschilds continue to control the global
monetary system through their alleged influence over the Federal Reserve
System.26
The price
of consols (UK perpetual bonds), 1812-1822
The more
prosaic reality was that the Rothschilds were able to build on their successes
during the final phase of the Napoleonic Wars to establish themselves as the
dominant players in an increasingly international London bond market. They did
this by establishing a capital base and an information network that were soon
far superior to those of their nearest rivals, the Barings. Between 1815 and
1859, it has been estimated that the London house issued fourteen different
sovereign bonds with a face value of nearly £43 million, more than half the
total issued by all banks in London.27 Although British
government bonds were the principal security they marketed to investors, they
also sold French, Prussian, Russian, Austrian, Neapolitan and Brazilian bonds.28 In
addition, they all but monopolized bond issuance by the Belgian government
after 1830. Typically, the Rothschilds would buy a tranche of new bonds
outright from a government, charging a commission for distributing these to
their network of brokers and investors throughout Europe, and remitting funds
to the government only when all the instalments had been received from buyers.
There would usually be a generous spread between the price the Rothschilds paid
the sovereign borrower and the price they asked of investors (with room for an
additional price ‘run up’ after the initial public offering). Of course, as we
have seen, there had been large-scale international lending before, notably in
Genoa, Antwerp and Amsterdam.29 But a distinguishing
feature of the London bond market after 1815 was the Rothschilds’ insistence
that most new borrowers issue bonds denominated in sterling, rather than their
own currency, and make interest payments in London or one of the other markets
where the Rothschilds had branches. A new standard was set by their 1818
initial public offering of Prussian 5 per cent bonds, which - after protracted
and often fraught negotiationsm - were issued not only
in London, but also in Frankfurt, Berlin, Hamburg and Amsterdam.30 In
his book On the Traffic in State Bonds (1825), the German
legal expert Johann Heinrich Bender singled out this as one of the Rothschilds’
most important financial innovations : ‘Any owner of government bonds . . . can
collect the interest at his convenience in several different places without any
effort.’31Bond issuance was by no means the only business the
Rothschilds did, to be sure: they were also bond traders, currency
arbitrageurs, bullion dealers and private bankers, as well as investors in
insurance, mines and railways. Yet the bond market remained their core
competence. Unlike their lesser competitors, the Rothschilds took pride in
dealing only in what would now be called investment grade securities. No bond
they issued in the 1820s was in default by 1829, despite a Latin American debt
crisis in the middle of the decade (the first of many).
With
success came ever greater wealth. When Nathan died in 1836, his personal
fortune was equivalent to 0.62 per cent of British national income. Between
1818 and 1852, the combined capital of the five Rothschild ‘houses’ (Frankfurt,
London, Naples, Paris and Vienna) rose from £1.8 million to £9.5 million. As
early as 1825 their combined capital was nine times greater than that of Baring
Brothers and the Banque de France. By 1899, at £41 million, it exceeded the
capital of the five biggest German joint-stock banks put together. Increasingly
the firm became a multinational asset manager for the wealth of the managers’
extended family. As their numbers grew from generation to generation, familial
unity was maintained by a combination of periodically revised contracts between
the five houses and a high level of intermarriage between cousins or between
uncles and nieces. Of twenty-one marriages involving descendants of Nathan’s
father Mayer Amschel Rothschild that were solemnized between 1824 and 1877, no
fewer than fifteen were between his direct descendants. In addition, the
family’s collective fidelity to the Jewish faith, at a time when some other
Jewish families were slipping into apostasy or mixed marriage, strengthened
their sense of common identity and purpose as ‘the Caucasian [Jewish] royal
family’.
Old Mayer
Amschel had repeatedly admonished his five sons: ‘If you can’t make yourself
loved, make yourself feared.’ As they bestrode the mid-nineteenth-century
financial world as masters of the bond market, the Rothschilds were already
more feared than loved. Reactionaries on the Right lamented the rise of a new
form of wealth, higher-yielding and more liquid than the landed estates of Europe’s
aristocratic elites. As Heinrich Heine discerned, there was something
profoundly revolutionary about the financial system the Rothschilds were
creating:
The system of paper securities frees . . . men
to choose whatever place of residence they like; they can live anywhere,
without working, from the interest on their bonds, their portable property, and
so they gather together and constitute the true power of our capital cities.
And we have long known what it portends when the most diverse energies can live
side by side, when there is such centralization of the intellectual and of
social authority.
In
Heine’s eyes, Rothschild could now be mentioned in the same breath as Richelieu
and Robespierre as one of the ‘three terroristic names that spell the gradual
annihilation of the old aristocracy’. Richelieu had destroyed its power;
Robespierre had decapitated its decadent remnant; now Rothschild was providing
Europe with a new social elite by
raising up the system of government bonds to
supreme power . . . [and] endowing money with the former privileges of land. To
be sure, he has thereby created a new aristocracy, but this is based on the
most unreliable of elements, on money . . . [which] is more fluid than water
and less steady than the air . . .32
Meanwhile,
Radicals on the Left bemoaned the rise of a new power in the realm of politics,
which wielded a veto power over government finance and hence over most policy.
Following the success of Rothschild bond issues for Austria, Prussia and
Russia, Nathan was caricatured as the insurance broker to the ‘Hollow
Alliance’, helping to protect Europe against liberal political fires.33 In
1821 he even received a death threat because of ‘his connexion with foreign
powers, and particularly the assistance rendered to Austria, on account of the
designs of that government against the liberties of Europe’.34 The
liberal historian Jules Michelet noted in his journal in 1842: ‘M. Rothschild
knows Europe prince by prince, and the bourse courtier by courtier. He has all
their accounts in his head, that of the courtiers and that of the kings; he
talks to them without even consulting his books. To one such he says: “Your
account will go into the red if you appoint such a minister.” ’35 Predictably,
the fact that the Rothschilds were Jewish gave a new impetus to deep-rooted
anti-Semitic prejudices. No sooner had the Rothschilds appeared on the American
scene in the 1830s than the governor of Mississippi was denouncing ‘Baron
Rothschild’ for having ‘the blood of Judas and Shylock flow[ing] in his veins,
and . . . unit[ing] the qualities of both his countrymen.’ Later in the
century, the Populist writer ‘Coin’ Harvey would depict the Rothschild bank as
a vast, black octopus stretching its tentacles around the world.36
Yet it
was the Rothschilds’ seeming ability to permit or prohibit wars at will that
seemed to arouse the most indignation. As early as 1828, Prince Pückler-Muskau
referred to ‘Rothschild . . . without whom no power in Europe today seems able
to make war’.37 One early-twentieth-century commentatorn pointedly
posed the question:
Does anyone seriously suppose that a great war
could be undertaken by any European State, or any great State loan subscribed,
if the house of Rothschild and its connexions set their face against it?38
It might,
indeed, be assumed that the Rothschilds needed war. It was war, after all, that
had generated Nathan Rothschild’s biggest deal. Without wars,
nineteenth-century states would have had little need to issue bonds. As we have
seen, however, wars tended to hit the price of existing bonds by increasing the
risk that (like sixteenth-century Venice) a debtor state would fail to meet its
interest payments in the event of defeat and losses of territory. By the middle
of the nineteenth century, the Rothschilds had evolved from traders into fund
managers, carefully tending to their own vast portfolio of government bonds.
Now, having made their money, they stood to lose more than they gained from
conflict. It was for this reason that they were consistently hostile to
strivings for national unity in both Italy and Germany. And it was for this
reason that they viewed with unease the descent of the United States into
internecine warfare. The Rothschilds had decided the outcome of the Napoleonic
Wars by putting their financial weight behind Britain. Now they would help
decide the outcome of the American Civil War - by choosing to sit on the
sidelines.
DRIVING
DIXIE DOWN
In May
1863, two years into the American Civil War, Major-General Ulysses S. Grant
captured Jackson, the Mississippi state capital, and forced the Confederate
army under Lieutenant-General John C. Pemberton to retreat westward to
Vicksburg on the banks of the Mississippi River. Surrounded, with Union
gunboats bombarding their positions from behind, Pemberton’s army repulsed two
Union assaults but they were finally starved into submission by a grinding
siege. On 4 July, Independence Day, Pemberton surrendered. From now on, the
Mississippi was firmly in the hands of the North. The South was literally split
in two.
The fall
of Vicksburg is always seen as one of the great turning points in the war. And
yet, from a financial point of view, it was really not the decisive one. The
key event had happened more than a year before, two hundred miles downstream
from Vicksburg, where the Mississippi joins the Gulf of Mexico. On 29 April
1862 Flag Officer David Farragut had run the guns of Fort Jackson and Fort St
Philip to seize control of New Orleans. This was a far less bloody and
protracted clash than the siege of Vicksburg, but equally disastrous for the
Southern cause.
The
finances of the Confederacy are one of the great might-have-beens of American
history.39 For, in the final analysis, it was as much a
lack of hard cash as a lack of industrial capacity or manpower that undercut
what was, in military terms, an impressive effort by the Southern states. At
the beginning of the war, in the absence of a pre-existing system of central
taxation, the fledgling Confederate Treasury had paid for its army by selling bonds
to its own citizens, in the form of two large loans for $15 million and $100
million. But there was a finite amount of liquid capital available in the
South, with its many self-contained farms and relatively small towns. To
survive, it was later alleged, the Confederacy turned to the Rothschilds, in
the hope that the world’s greatest financial dynasty might help them beat the
North as they had helped Wellington beat Napoleon at Waterloo.
The
suggestion was not altogether fanciful. In New York, the Rothschild agent
August Belmont had watched with horror as the United States slid into Civil
War. As the Democratic Party’s national chairman, he had been a leading
supporter of Stephen A. Douglas, Abraham Lincoln’s opponent in the presidential
election of 1860. Belmont remained a vocal critic of what he called Lincoln’s
‘fatal policy of confiscation and forcible emancipation’. 40 Salomon
de Rothschild, James’s third son, had also expressed pro-Southern sympathies in
his letters home before the war began.41Some Northern
commentators drew the obvious inference: the Rothschilds were backing the
South. ‘Belmont, the Rothschilds, and the whole tribe of Jews . . . have been
buying up Confederate bonds,’ thundered the Chicago Tribune in
1864. One Lincoln supporter accused the ‘Jews, Jeff Davis [the Confederate
president] and the devil’ of being an unholy trinity directed against the
Union.42 When he visited London in 1863, Belmont himself
told Lionel de Rothschild that ‘soon the North would be conquered’. (It merely
stoked the fires of suspicion that the man charged with recruiting Britain to
the South’s cause, the Confederate Secretary of State Judah Benjamin, was
himself a Jew.)
In
reality, however, the Rothschilds opted not to back the South. Why? Perhaps it
was because they felt a genuine distaste for the institution of slavery. But of
at least equal importance was a sense that the Confederacy was not a good
credit risk (after all, the Confederate president Jefferson Davis had openly
advocated the repudiation of state debts when he was a US senator). That
mistrust seemed to be widely shared in Europe. When the Confederacy tried to
sell conventional bonds in European markets, investors showed little
enthusiasm. But the Southerners had an ingenious trick up their sleeves. The
trick (like the sleeves themselves) was made of cotton, the key to the
Confederate economy and by far the South’s largest export. The idea was to use
the South’s cotton crop not just as a source of export earnings, but as
collateral for a new kind of cotton-backed bond. When the obscure French firm
of Emile Erlanger and Co. started issuing cotton-backed bonds on the South’s
behalf, the response in London and Amsterdam was more positive. The most
appealing thing about these sterling bonds, which had a 7 per cent coupon and a
maturity of twenty years, was that they could be converted into cotton at the
pre-war price of six pence a pound. Despite the South’s military setbacks, they
retained their value for most of the war for the simple reason that the price
of the underlying security, cotton, was rising as a consequence of increased
wartime demand. Indeed, the price of the bonds actually doubled between
December 1863 and September 1864, despite the Confederate defeats at Gettysburg
and Vicksburg, because the price of cotton was soaring.43 Moreover,
the South was in the happy position of being able to raise that price still
further - by restricting the cotton supply.
In 1860
the port of Liverpool was the main artery for the supply of imported cotton to
the British textile industry, then the mainstay of the Victorian industrial
economy. More than 80 per cent of these imports came from the southern United
States. The Confederate leaders believed this gave them the leverage to bring
Britain into the war on their side. To ratchet up the pressure, they decided to
impose an embargo on all cotton exports to Liverpool. The effects were
devastating. Cotton prices soared from 6¼d per pound to 27¼d. Imports from the
South slumped from 2.6 million bales in 1860 to less than 72,000 in 1862. A
typical English cotton mill like the one that has been preserved at Styal,
south of Manchester, employed around 400 workers, but that was just a fraction
of the 300,000 people employed by King Cotton across Lancashire as a whole. Without
cotton there was literally nothing for those workers to do. By late 1862 half
the workforce had been laid off; around a quarter of the entire population of
Lancashire was on poor relief.44 They called it the
cotton famine. This, however, was a man-made famine. And the men who made it
seemed to be achieving their goal. Not only did the embargo cause unemployment,
hunger and riots in the north of England; the shortage of cotton also drove up
the price and hence the value of the South’s cotton-backed bonds, making them
an irresistibly attractive investment for key members of the British political
elite. The future Prime Minister, William Ewart Gladstone, bought some, as did
the editor of The Times, John Delane.45
Yet the
South’s ability to manipulate the bond market depended on one overriding
condition: that investors should be able to take physical possession of the
cotton which underpinned the bonds if the South failed to make its interest
payments. Collateral is, after all, only good if a creditor can get his hands
on it. And that is why the fall of New Orleans in April 1862 was the real
turning point in the American Civil War. With the South’s main port in Union
hands, any investor who wanted to get hold of Southern cotton had to run the
Union’s naval blockade not once but twice, in and out. Given the North’s
growing naval power in and around the Mississippi, that was not an enticing
prospect.
If the
South had managed to hold on to New Orleans until the cotton harvest had been
offloaded to Europe, they might have managed to sell more than £3 million of
cotton bonds in London. Maybe even the risk-averse Rothschilds might have come
off the financial fence. As it was, they dismissed the Erlanger loan as being
‘of so speculative a nature that it was very likely to attract all wild
speculators . . . we do not hear of any respectable people having anything to
do with it’.46 The Confederacy had overplayed its hand.
They had turned off the cotton tap, but then lost the ability to turn it back
on. By 1863 the mills of Lancashire had found new sources of cotton in China,
Egypt and India. And now investors were rapidly losing faith in the South’s
cotton-backed bonds. The consequences for the Confederate economy were
disastrous.
With its
domestic bond market exhausted and only two paltry foreign loans, the
Confederate government was forced to print unbacked paper dollars to pay for
the war and its other expenses, 1.7 billion dollars’ worth in all. Both sides
in the Civil War had to print money, it is true. But by the end of the war the
Union’s ‘greenback’ dollars were still worth about 50 cents in gold, whereas
the Confederacy’s ‘greybacks’ were worth just one cent, despite a vain attempt
at currency reform in 1864.47 The situation was worsened
by the ability of Southern states and municipalities to print paper money of
their own; and by rampant forgery, since Confederate notes were crudely made
and easy to copy. With ever more paper money chasing ever fewer goods,
inflation exploded. Prices in the South rose by around 4,000 per cent during
the Civil War.48 By contrast, prices in the North rose
by just 60 per cent. Even before the surrender of the principal Confederate
armies in April 1865, the economy of the South was collapsing, with
hyperinflation as the sure harbinger of defeat.
The
Rothschilds had been right. Those who had invested in Confederate bonds ended
up losing everything, since the victorious North pledged not to honour the
debts of the South. In the end, there had been no option but to finance the
Southern war effort by printing money. It would not be the last time in history
that an attempt to buck the bond market would end in ruinous inflation and
military humiliation.
THE
EUTHANASIA OF THE RENTIER
The fate
of those who lost their shirts on Confederate bonds was not especially unusual
in the nineteenth century. The Confederacy was far from the only state in the
Americas to end up disappointing its bondholders; it was merely the
northernmost delinquent. South of the Rio Grande, debt defaults and currency
depreciations verged on the commonplace. The experience of Latin America in the
nineteenth century in many ways foreshadowed problems that would become almost
universal in the middle of the twentieth century. Partly this was because the
social class that was most likely to invest in bonds - and therefore to have an
interest in prompt interest payment in a sound currency - was weaker there than
elsewhere. Partly it was because Latin American republics were among the first
to discover that it was relatively painless to default when a substantial
proportion of bondholders were foreign. It was no mere accident that the first
great Latin American debt crisis happened as early as 1826-9, when Peru,
Colombia, Chile, Mexico, Guatemala and Argentina all defaulted on loans issued
in London just a few years before.49
In many
ways, it was true that the bond market was powerful. By the later nineteenth
century, countries that defaulted on their debts risked economic sanctions, the
imposition of foreign control over their finances and even, in at least five
cases, military intervention.50 It is hard to believe
that Gladstone would have ordered the invasion of Egypt in 1882 if the Egyptian
government had not threatened to renege on its obligations to European
bondholders, himself among them. Bringing an ‘emerging market’ under the aegis
of the British Empire was the surest way to remove political risk from
investors’ concerns.51 Even those outside the Empire
risked a visit from a gunboat if they defaulted, as Venezuela discovered in
1902, when a joint naval expedition by Britain, Germany and Italy temporarily
blockaded the country’s ports. The United States was especially energetic (and
effective) in protecting bondholders’ interests in Central America and the
Caribbean.52
But in one
crucial respect the bond market was potentially vulnerable. Investors in the
City of London, the biggest international financial market in the world
throughout the nineteenth century, were wealthy but not numerous. In the early
nineteenth century the number of British bondholders may have been fewer than
250,000, barely 2 per cent of the population. Yet their wealth was more than
double the entire national income of the United Kingdom; their income in the
region of 7 per cent of national income. In 1822 this income - the interest on
the national debt - amounted to roughly half of total public spending, yet more
than two thirds of tax revenue was indirect and hence fell on consumption. Even
as late as 1870 these proportions were still, respectively, a third and more
than half. It would be quite hard to devise a more regressive fiscal system,
with taxes imposed on the necessities of the many being used to finance
interest payments to the very few. Small wonder Radicals like William Cobbett
were incensed. ‘A national debt, and all the taxation and gambling belonging to
it,’ Cobbett declared in his Rural Rides (1830), ‘have a
natural tendency to draw wealth into great masses . . . for the gain of
a few.’53 In the absence of political reform, he
warned, the entire country would end up in the hands of ‘those who have had
borrowed from them the money to uphold this monster of a system . . . the
loan-jobbers, stock-jobbers . . . Jews and the whole tribe of tax-eaters’.54
Such
tirades did little to weaken the position of the class known in France as
the rentiers - the recipients of interest on government bonds
like the French rente. On the contrary, the decades after 1830 were
a golden age for the rentier in Europe. Defaults became less
and less frequent. Money, thanks to the gold standard, became more and more
dependable.55 This triumph of the rentier,
despite the generalized widening of electoral franchises, was remarkable. True,
the rise of savings banks (which were often mandated to hold government bonds
as their principal assets) gave new segments of society indirect exposure to,
and therefore stakes in, the bond market. But fundamentally the rentiers remained
an elite of Rothschilds, Barings and Gladstones - socially, politically, but
above all economically intertwined. What ended their dominance was not the rise
of democracy or socialism, but a fiscal and monetary catastrophe for which the
European elites were themselves responsible. That catastrophe was the First
World War.
‘Inflation’,
wrote Milton Friedman in a famous definition, ‘is always and everywhere a
monetary phenomenon, in the sense that it cannot occur without a more rapid
increase in the quantity of money than in output.’ What happened in all the
combatant states during and after the First World War illustrates this pretty
well. There were essentially five steps to high inflation:
1. War
led not only to shortages of goods but also to
2.
short-term government borrowing from the central bank,
3. which
effectively turned debt into cash, thereby expanding the money supply,
4.
causing public expectations of inflation to shift and the demand for cash
balances to fall
5. and
prices of goods to rise.o
Pure
monetary theory, however, cannot explain why in one country the inflationary
process proceeds so much further or faster than in another. Nor can it explain
why the consequences of inflation vary so much from case to case. If one adds
together the total public expenditures of the major combatant powers between
1914 and 1918, Britain spent rather more than Germany and France much more than
Russia. Expressed in terms of dollars, the public debts of Britain, France and
the United States increased much more between April 1914 and March 1918 than
that of Germany.56True, the volume of banknotes in
circulation rose by more in Germany between 1913 and 1918 (1,040 per cent) than
in Britain (708 per cent) or France (386 per cent), but for Bulgaria the figure
was 1,116 per cent and for Romania 961 per cent.57 Relative
to 1913, wholesale prices had risen further by 1918 in Italy, France and
Britain than in Germany. The cost-of-living index for Berlin in 1918 was 2.3
times higher than its pre-war level; for London it was little different (2.1
times higher).58 Why, then, was it Germany that plunged
into hyperinflation after the First World War? Why was it the mark that
collapsed into worthlessness? The key lies in the role of the bond market in
war and post-war finance.
All the
warring countries went on war bonds sales-drives during the war, persuading
thousands of small savers who had never previously purchased government bonds
that it was their patriotic duty to do so. Unlike Britain, France, Italy and
Russia, however, Germany did not have access to the international bond market
during the war (having initially spurned the New York market and then been shut
out of it). While the Entente powers could sell bonds in the United States or
throughout the capital-rich British Empire, the Central powers (Germany,
Austria-Hungary and Turkey) were thrown back on their own resources. Berlin and
Vienna were important financial centres, but they lacked the depth of London,
Paris and New York. As a result, the sale of war bonds grew gradually more
difficult for the Germans and their allies, as the appetite of domestic
investors became sated. Much sooner, and to a much greater extent than in
Britain, the German and Austrian authorities had to turn to their central banks
for short-term funding. The growth of the volume of Treasury bills in the
central bank’s hands was a harbinger of inflation because, unlike the sale of
bonds to the public, exchanging these bills for banknotes increased the money
supply. By the end of the war, roughly a third of the Reich debt was ‘floating’
or unfunded, and a substantial monetary overhang had been created, which only
wartime price controls prevented from manifesting itself in higher inflation.
Defeat
itself had a high price. All sides had reassured taxpayers and bondholders that
the enemy would pay for the war. Now the bills fell due in Berlin. One way of
understanding the post-war hyperinflation is therefore as a form of state
bankruptcy. Those who had bought war bonds had invested in a promise of victory;
defeat and revolution represented a national insolvency, the brunt of which
necessarily had to be borne by the Reich’s creditors. Quite apart from defeat,
the revolutionary events between November 1918 and January 1919 were scarcely
calculated to reassure investors. Nor was the peace conference at Versailles,
which imposed an unspecified reparations liability on the fledgling Weimar
Republic. When the total indemnity was finally fixed in 1921, the Germans found
themselves saddled with a huge new external debt with a nominal capital value
of 132 billion ‘gold marks’ (pre-war marks), equivalent to more than three
times national income. Although not all this new debt was immediately
interest-bearing, the scheduled reparations payments accounted for more than a
third of all Reich expenditure in 1921 and 1922. No investor who contemplated
Germany’s position in the summer of 1921 could have felt optimistic, and such
foreign capital as did flow into the country after the war was speculative or
‘hot’ money, which soon departed when the going got tough.
Yet it
would be wrong to see the hyperinflation of 1923 as a simple consequence of the
Versailles Treaty. That was how the Germans liked to see it, of course. Their
claim throughout the post-war period was that the reparations burden created an
unsustainable current account deficit; that there was no alternative but to
print yet more paper marks in order to finance it; that the inflation was a
direct consequence of the resulting depreciation of the mark. All of this was
to overlook the domestic political roots of the monetary crisis. The Weimar tax
system was feeble, not least because the new regime lacked legitimacy among
higher income groups who declined to pay the taxes imposed on them. At the same
time, public money was spent recklessly, particularly on generous wage
settlements for public sector unions. The combination of insufficient taxation
and excessive spending created enormous deficits in 1919 and 1920 (in excess of
10 per cent of net national product), before the victors had even presented
their reparations bill. The deficit in 1923, when Germany had suspended
reparations payments, was even larger. Moreover, those in charge of Weimar
economic policy in the early 1920s felt they had little incentive to stabilize
German fiscal and monetary policy, even when an opportunity presented itself in
the middle of 1920.59 A common calculation among
Germany’s financial elites was that runaway currency depreciation would force
the Allied powers into revising the reparations settlement, since the effect
would be to cheapen German exports relative to American, British and French
manufactures. It was true, as far as it went, that the downward slide of the
mark boosted German exports. What the Germans overlooked was that the inflation-induced
boom of 1920-22, at a time when the US and UK economies were in the depths of a
post-war recession, caused an even bigger surge in imports, thus negating the
economic pressure they had hoped to exert. At the heart of the German
hyperinflation was a miscalculation. When the French cottoned on to the
insincerity of official German pledges to fulfil their reparations commitments,
they drew the conclusion that reparations would have to be collected by force
and invaded the industrial Ruhr region. The Germans reacted by proclaiming a
general strike (‘passive resistance’), which they financed with yet more paper
money. The hyperinflationary endgame had now arrived.
Inflation
is a monetary phenomenon, as Milton Friedman said. But hyperinflation is always
and everywhere a political phenomenon, in the sense that it
cannot occur without a fundamental malfunction of a country’s political
economy. There surely were less catastrophic ways to settle the conflicting
claims of domestic and foreign creditors on the diminished national income of
postwar Germany. But a combination of internal gridlock and external defiance -
rooted in the refusal of many Germans to accept that their empire had been
fairly beaten - led to the worst of all possible outcomes: a complete collapse
of the currency and of the economy itself. By the end of 1923 there were
approximately 4.97 × 1020 marks in circulation.
Twenty-billion mark notes were in everyday use. The annual inflation rate
reached a peak of 182 billion per cent. Prices were on average 1.26 trillion times
higher than they had been in 1913. True, there had been some short-term
benefits. By discouraging saving and encouraging consumption, accelerating
inflation had stimulated output and employment until the last quarter of 1922.
The depreciating mark, as we have seen, had boosted German exports. Yet the
collapse of 1923 was all the more severe for having been postponed. Industrial
production dropped to half its 1913 level. Unemployment soared to, at its peak,
a quarter of trade union members, with another quarter working short time.
Worst of all was the social and psychological trauma caused by the crisis.
‘Inflation is a crowd phenomenon in the strictest and most concrete sense of
the word,’ Elias Canetti later wrote of his experiences as a young man in
inflation-stricken Frankfurt. ‘[It is] a witches’ sabbath of devaluation where
men and the units of their money have the strongest effects on each other. The
one stands for the other, men feeling themselves as “bad” as their money; and
this becomes worse and worse. Together they are all at its mercy and all feel
equally worthless.’60
Worthlessness
was the hyperinflation’s principal product. Not only was money rendered
worthless; so too were all the forms of wealth and income fixed in terms of
that money. That included bonds. The hyperinflation could not wipe out
Germany’s external debt, which had been fixed in pre-war currency. But it could
and did wipe out all the internal debt that had been accumulated during and
after the war, levelling the debt mountain like some devastating economic
earthquake. The effect was akin to a tax: a tax not only on bondholders but
also on anyone living on a fixed cash income. This amounted to a great
levelling, since it affected primarily the upper middle classes: rentiers,
senior civil servants, professionals. Only entrepreneurs were in a position to
insulate themselves by adjusting prices upwards, hoarding dollars, investing in
‘real assets’ (such as houses or factories) and paying off debts in depreciating
banknotes. The enduring economic legacy of the hyperinflation was bad enough:
weakened banks and chronically high interest rates, which now incorporated a
substantial inflation risk premium. But it was the social and political
consequences of the German hyperinflation that were the most grievous. The
English economist John Maynard Keynes had theorized in 1923 that the
‘euthanasia of the rentier’ through inflation was preferable to
mass unemployment through deflation - ‘because it is worse in an impoverished
world to provoke unemployment than to disappoint the rentier’.61 Yet
four years earlier, he himself had given a vivid account of the negative
consequences of inflation:
By a continuing process of inflation,
governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the
wealth of their citizens. By this method, they not only confiscate, but they
confiscate arbitrarily;
and, while the process impoverishes many, it actually enriches some. The sight
of this arbitrary rearrangement of riches strikes not only at security, but at
confidence in the equity of the existing distribution of wealth. Those to whom
the system brings windfalls . . . become ‘profiteers’, who are the object of
the hatred of the bourgeoisie, whom the inflationism has impoverished not less
than of the proletariat. As the inflation proceeds . . . all permanent
relations between debtors and creditors, which form the ultimate foundation of
capitalism, become so utterly disordered as to be almost meaningless . . .62
It was to
Lenin that Keynes attributed the insight that ‘There is no subtler, no surer
means of overturning the existing basis of society than to debauch the
currency.’ No record survives of Lenin saying any such thing, but his fellow
Bolshevik Yevgeni Preobrazhenskyp did describe the
banknote-printing press as ‘that machine-gun of the Commissariat of Finance
which poured fire into the rear of the bourgeois system’.63
The
Russian example is a reminder that Germany was not the only vanquished country
to suffer hyperinflation after the First World War. Austria - as well as the
newly independent Hungary and Poland - also suffered comparably bad currency
collapses between 1917 and 1924. In the Russian case, hyperinflation came after
the Bolsheviks had defaulted outright on the entire Tsarist debt. Bondholders
would suffer similar fates in the aftermath of the Second World War, when
Germany, Hungary and Greece all saw their currencies and bond markets collapse.q
If
hyperinflation were exclusively associated with the costs of losing world wars,
it would be relatively easy to understand. Yet there is a puzzle. In more
recent times, a number of countries have been driven to default on their debts
- either directly by suspending interest payments, or indirectly by debasing the
currency in which the debts are denominated - as a result of far less serious
disasters. Why is it that the spectre of hyperinflation has not been banished
along with the spectre of global conflict?
PIMCO
boss Bill Gross began his money-making career as a blackjack player in Las
Vegas. To his eyes, there is always an element of gambling involved when an
investor buys a bond. Part of that gamble is that an upsurge in inflation will
not consume the value of the bond’s annual interest payments. As Gross explains
it, ‘If inflation goes up to ten per cent and the value of a fixed rate
interest is only five, then that basically means that the bond holder is
falling behind inflation by five per cent.’ As we have seen, the danger that
rising inflation poses is that it erodes the purchasing power of both the
capital sum invested and the interest payments due. And that is why, at the
first whiff of higher inflation, bond prices tend to fall. Even as recently as
the 1970s, as inflation soared around the world, the bond market made a Nevada
casino look like a pretty safe place to invest your money. Gross vividly
recalls the time when US inflation was surging into double digits, peaking at
just under 15 per cent in April 1980. As he puts it, ‘that was very
bond-unfriendly, and it produced . . . perhaps the worst bond bear market not
just in memory but in history.’ To be precise, real annual returns on US
government bonds in the 1970s were minus 3 per cent, almost as bad as during
the inflationary years of the world wars. Today, only a handful of countries
have inflation rates above 10 per cent and only one, Zimbabwe, is afflicted
with hyperinflation.r But back in 1979 at least seven
countries had an annual inflation rate above 50 per cent and more than sixty
countries, including Britain and the United States, had inflation in double
digits. Among the countries worst affected, none suffered more severe long-term
damage than Argentina.
Once,
Argentina was a byword for prosperity. The country’s very name means the land
of silver. The river on whose banks the capital Buenos Aires stands is the Rio
de la Plata - in English the Silver River - a reference not to its colour,
which is muddy brown, but to the silver deposits supposed to lie upstream. In
1913, according to recent estimates, Argentina was one of the ten richest
countries in the world. Outside the English-speaking world, per capita gross
domestic product was higher in only Switzerland, Belgium, the Netherlands and
Denmark. Between 1870 and 1913, Argentina’s economy had grown faster than those
of both the United States and Germany. There was almost as much foreign capital
invested there as in Canada. It is no coincidence that there were once two
Harrods stores in the world: one in Knightsbridge, in London, the other on the Avenida
Florida, in the heart of Buenos Aires. Argentina could credibly aspire to be
the United Kingdom, if not the United States, of the southern hemisphere. In
February 1946, when the newly elected president General Juan Domingo Perón
visited the central bank in Buenos Aires, he was astonished at what he saw.
‘There is so much gold,’ he marvelled, ‘you can hardly walk through the
corridors.’
The
economic history of Argentina in the twentieth century is an object lesson that
all the resources in the world can be set at nought by financial mismanagement.
Particularly after the Second World War the country consistently underperformed
its neighbours and most of the rest of the world. So miserably did it fare in
the 1960s and 1970s, for example, that its per capita GDP was the same in 1988
as it had been in 1959. By 1998 it had sunk to 34 per cent of the US level,
compared with 72 per cent in 1913. It had been overtaken by, among others,
Singapore, Japan, Taiwan and South Korea - not forgetting, most painful of all,
the country next door, Chile. What went wrong? One possible answer is
inflation, which was in double digits between 1945 and 1952, between 1956 and
1968 and between 1970 and 1974; and in treble (or quadruple) digits between
1975 and 1990, peaking at an annual rate of 5,000 per cent in 1989. Another
answer is debt default: Argentina let down foreign creditors in 1982, 1989,
2002 and 2004. Yet these answers will not quite suffice. Argentina had suffered
double-digit inflation in at least eight years between 1870 and 1914. It had
defaulted on its debts at least twice in the same period. To understand
Argentina’s economic decline, it is once again necessary to see that inflation
was a political as much as a monetary phenomenon.
An
oligarchy of landowners had sought to base the country’s economy on
agricultural exports to the English-speaking world, a model that failed
comprehensively in the Depression. Large-scale immigration without (as in North
America) the freeing of agricultural land for settlement had created a
disproportionately large urban working class that was highly susceptible to
populist mobilization. Repeated military interventions in politics, beginning
with the coup that installed José F. Uriburu in 1930, paved the way for a new
kind of quasi-fascistic politics under Perón, who seemed to offer something for
everyone: better wages and conditions for workers and protective tariffs for
industrialists. The anti-labour alternative to Péron, which was attempted
between 1955 (when he was deposed) and 1966, relied on currency devaluation to
try to reconcile the interests of agriculture and industry. Another military
coup in 1966 promised technological modernization but instead delivered more
devaluation, and higher inflation. Perón’s return in 1973 was a fiasco,
coinciding as it did with the onset of a global upsurge in inflation. Annual
inflation surged to 444 per cent. Yet another military coup plunged Argentina
into violence as the Proceso de Reorganización Nacional (National
Reorganization Process) condemned thousands to arbitrary detention and
‘disappearance’. In economic terms, the junta achieved precisely nothing other
than to saddle Argentina with a rapidly growing external debt, which by 1984
exceeded 60 per cent of GDP (though this was less than half the peak level of
indebtedness attained in the early 1900s). As so often in inflationary crises,
war played a part: internally against supposed subversives, externally against
Britain over the Falkland Islands. Yet it would be wrong to see this as yet
another case of a defeated regime liquidating its debts through inflation. What
made Argentina’s inflation so unmanageable was not war, but the constellation
of social forces: the oligarchs, the caudillos, the producers’
interest groups and the trade unions - not forgetting the impoverished
underclass or descamizados (literally the shirtless). To put
it simply, there was no significant group with an interest in price stability.
Owners of capital were attracted to deficits and devaluation; sellers of labour
grew accustomed to a wage-price spiral. The gradual shift from financing
government deficits domestically to financing them externally meant that
bondholding was out-sourced. 64 It is against this
background that the failure of successive plans for Argentine currency
stabilization must be understood.
In his
short story ‘The Garden of Forking Paths’, Argentina’s greatest writer Jorge
Luis Borges imagined the writing of a Chinese sage, Ts’ui Pên:
In all fictional works, each time a man is
confronted with several alternatives, he chooses one and eliminates the others;
in the fiction of Ts’ui Pên, he chooses - simultaneously - all of them. He creates, in this way, diverse
futures; diverse times which themselves also proliferate and fork . . . In the
work of Ts’ui Pên, all possible outcomes occur; each one is the point of
departure for other forkings . . . [Ts’ui Pên] did not believe in a uniform,
absolute time. He believed in an infinite series of times, in a growing,
dizzying net of divergent, convergent and parallel times.65
This is
not a bad metaphor for Argentine financial history in the past thirty years.
Where Bernardo Grinspun attempted debt rescheduling and Keynesian demand
management, Juan Sourrouille tried currency reform (the Austral Plan) along
with wage and price controls. Neither was able to lead the critical interest
groups down his own forking path. Public expenditure continued to exceed tax
revenue; arguments for a premature end to wage and price controls prevailed;
inflation resumed after only the most fleeting of stabilizations. The forking
paths finally and calamitously reconverged in 1989: the annus mirabilis in
Eastern Europe; the annus horribilis in Argentina.
In
February 1989 Argentina was suffering one of the hottest summers on record. The
electricity system in Buenos Aires struggled to cope. People grew accustomed to
five-hour power cuts. Banks and foreign exchange houses were ordered to close
as the government tried to prevent the currency’s exchange rate from
collapsing. It failed: in the space of just a month the austral fell 140 per
cent against the dollar. At the same time, the World Bank froze lending to
Argentina, saying that the government had failed to tackle its bloated public
sector deficit. Private sector lenders were no more enthusiastic. Investors
were hardly likely to buy bonds with the prospect that inflation would wipe out
their real value within days. As fears grew that the central bank’s reserves
were running out, bond prices plunged. There was only one option left for a desperate
government: the printing press. But even that failed. On Friday 28 April
Argentina literally ran out of money. ‘It’s a physical problem,’ Central Bank
Vice-President Roberto Eilbaum told a news conference. The mint had literally
run out of paper and the printers had gone on strike. ‘I don’t know how we’re
going to do it, but the money has got to be there on Monday,’ he confessed.
By June,
with the monthly inflation rate rising above 100 per cent,
popular frustration was close to boiling point. Already in April customers in
one Buenos Aires supermarket had overturned trolleys full of goods after the
management announced over a loudspeaker that all prices would immediately be
raised by 30 per cent. For two days in June crowds in Argentina’s second largest
city, Rosario, ran amok in an eruption of rioting and looting that left at
least fourteen people dead. As in the Weimar Republic, however, the principal
losers of Argentina’s hyperinflation were not ordinary workers, who stood a
better chance of matching price hikes with pay rises, but those reliant on
incomes fixed in cash terms, like civil servants or academics on inflexible
salaries, or pensioners living off the interest on their savings. And, as in
1920s Germany, the principal beneficiaries were those with large debts, which
were effectively wiped out by inflation. Among those beneficiaries was the
government itself, in so far as the money it owed was denominated in australes.
Yet not
all Argentina’s debts could be got rid of so easily. By 1983 the country’s
external debt, which was denominated in US dollars, stood at $46 billion,
equivalent to around 40 per cent of national output. No matter what happened to
the Argentine currency, this dollar-denominated debt stayed the same. Indeed,
it tended to grow as desperate governments borrowed yet more dollars. By 1989
the country’s external debt was over $65 billion. Over the next decade it would
continue to grow until it reached $155 billion. Domestic creditors had already
been mulcted by inflation. But only default could rid Argentina of its foreign
debt burden. As we have seen, Argentina had gone down this road more than once
before. In 1890 Baring Brothers had been brought to the brink of bankruptcy by
its investments in Argentine securities (notably a failed issue of bonds for
the Buenos Aires Water Supply and Drainage Company) when the Argentine
government defaulted on its external debt. It was the Barings’ old rivals the
Rothschilds who persuaded the British government to contribute £1 million
towards what became a £17 million bailout fund, on the principle that the
collapse of Barings would be ‘a terrific calamity for English commerce all over
the world’.66 And it was also the first Lord Rothschild
who chaired a committee of bankers set up to impose reform on the wayward
Argentines. Future loans would be conditional on a currency reform that pegged
the peso to gold by means of an independent and inflexible currency board.67 A
century later, however, the Rothschilds were more interested in Argentine vineyards
than in Argentine debt. It was the International Monetary Fund that had to
perform the thankless task of trying to avert (or at least mitigate the effects
of) an Argentine default. Once again the remedy was a currency board, this time
pegging the currency to the dollar.
When the
new peso convertible was introduced by Finance Minister
Domingo Cavallo in 1991, it was the sixth Argentine currency in the space of a
century. Yet this remedy, too, ended in failure. True, by 1996 inflation had
been brought down to zero; indeed, it turned negative in 1999. But unemployment
stood at 15 per cent and income inequality was only marginally better than in
Nigeria. Moreover, monetary stricture was never accompanied by fiscal
stricture; public debt rose from 35 per cent of GDP at the end of 1994 to 64
per cent at the end of 2001 as central and provincial governments alike tapped
the international bond market rather than balance their budgets. In short,
despite pegging the currency and even slashing inflation, Cavallo had failed to
change the underlying social and institutional drivers that had caused so many
monetary crises in the past. The stage was set for yet another Argentine
default, and yet another currency. After two bailouts in January ($15 billion)
and May ($8 billion), the IMF declined to throw a third lifeline. On 23
December 2001, at the end of a year in which per capita GDP had declined by an
agonizing 12 per cent, the government announced a moratorium on the entirety of
its foreign debt, including bonds worth $81 billion: in nominal terms the
biggest debt default in history.
The
history of Argentina illustrates that the bond market is less powerful than it
might first appear. The average 295 basis point spread between Argentine and
British bonds in the 1880s scarcely compensated investors like the Barings for
the risks they were running by investing in Argentina. In the same way, the
average 664 basis point spread between Argentine and US bonds from 1998 to 2000
significantly underpriced the risk of default as the Cavallo currency peg began
to crumble. When the default was announced, the spread rose to 5,500; by March
2002 it exceeded 7,000 basis points. After painfully protracted negotiations
(there were 152 varieties of paper involved, denominated in six different
currencies and governed by eight jurisdictions) the majority of approximately
500,000 creditors agreed to accept new bonds worth roughly 35 cents on the
dollar, one of the most drastic ‘haircuts’ in the history of the bond market.68 So
successful did Argentina’s default prove (economic growth has since surged
while bond spreads are back in the 300-500 basis point range) that many
economists were left to ponder why any sovereign debtor ever honours its
commitments to foreign bondholders.69
THE
RESURRECTION OF THE RENTIER
In the
1920s, as we have seen, Keynes had predicted the ‘euthanasia of the rentier’,
anticipating that inflation would eventually eat up all the paper wealth of
those who had put their money in government bonds. In our time, however, we
have seen a miraculous resurrection of the bondholder. After the Great
Inflation of the 1970s, the past thirty years have seen one country after
another reduce inflation to single digits.70 (Even in
Argentina, the official inflation rate is below 10 per cent, though unofficial
estimates compiled by the provinces of Mendoza and San Luis put it above 20 per
cent.) And, as inflation has fallen, so bonds have rallied in what has been one
of the great bond bull markets of modern history. Even more remarkably, despite
the spectacular Argentine default - not to mention Russia’s in 1998 - the
spreads on emerging market bonds have trended steadily downwards, reaching lows
in early 2007 that had not been seen since before the First World War, implying
an almost unshakeable confidence in the economic future. Rumours of the death
of Mr Bond have clearly proved to be exaggerated.
Inflation
has come down partly because many of the items we buy, from clothes to
computers, have got cheaper as a result of technological innovation and the
relocation of production to low-wage economies in Asia. It has also been
reduced because of a worldwide transformation in monetary policy, which began
with the monetarist-inspired increases in short-term rates implemented by the
Bank of England and the Federal Reserve in the late 1970s and early 1980s, and
continued with the spread of central bank independence and explicit targets in
the 1990s. Just as importantly, as the Argentine case shows, some of the
structural drivers of inflation have also weakened. Trade unions have become
less powerful. Loss-making state industries have been privatized. But, perhaps
most importantly of all, the social constituency with an interest in positive
real returns on bonds has grown. In the developed world a rising share of
wealth is held in the form of private pension funds and other savings
institutions that are required, or at least expected, to hold a high proportion
of their assets in the form of government bonds and other fixed income
securities. In 2007 a survey of pension funds in eleven major economies
revealed that bonds accounted for more than a quarter of their assets,
substantially lower than in past decades, but still a substantial share.71 With
every passing year, the proportion of the population living off the income from
such funds goes up, as the share of retirees increases.
Which
brings us back to Italy, the land where the bond market was born. In 1965, on
the eve of the Great Inflation, just 10 per cent of Italians were aged 65 or
over. Today the proportion is twice that: around a fifth. And by 2050 it is
projected by the United Nations to be just under a third. In such a greying
society, there is a huge and growing need for fixed income securities, and for
low inflation to ensure that the interest they pay retains its purchasing
power. As more and more people leave the workforce, recurrent public sector
deficits ensure that the bond market will never be short of new bonds to sell.
And the fact that Italy has surrendered its monetary sovereignty to the
European Central Bank means that there should never be another opportunity for
Italian politicians to print money and set off the inflationary spiral.
That does
not mean, however, that the bond market rules the world in the sense that James
Carville meant. Indeed, the kind of discipline he associated with the bond
market in the 1990s has been conspicuous by its absence under President
Clinton’s successor, George W. Bush. Just months before President Bush’s
election, on 7 September 2000, the National Debt Clock in New York’s Times
Square was shut down. On that day it read as follows: ‘Our national debt:
$5,676,989,904,887. Your family share: $73,733.’ After three years of budget
surpluses, both candidates for the presidency were talking as if paying off the
national debt was a viable project. According to CNN
Democratic presidential nominee Al Gore has
outlined a plan that he says would eliminate the debt by 2012. Senior economic
advisers to Texas Governor and Republican presidential candidate George W. Bush
agree with the principle of paying down the debt but have not committed to a
specific date for eliminating it.72
That lack
of commitment on the latter candidate’s part was by way of being a hint. Since
Bush entered the White House, his administration has run a budget deficit in
seven out of eight years. The federal debt has increased from $5 trillion to
more than $9 trillion. The Congressional Budget Office forecasts a continued
rise to more than $12 trillion by 2017. Yet, far from punishing this
profligacy, the bond market has positively rewarded it. Between December 2000
and June 2003, the yield on ten-year Treasury bonds declined from
5.24 per cent to 3.33 per cent, and remains just above 4 per cent at the time
of writing.
It is,
however, impossible to make sense of this ‘conundrum’ - as Alan Greenspan
called this failure of bond yields to respond to short-term interest rate rises73 -
by studying the bond market in isolation. We therefore turn now from the market
for government debt to its younger and in many ways more dynamic sibling: the
market for shares in corporate equity, known colloquially as the stock market.
NOTES
1 David Wessel and
Thomas T. Vogel Jr., ‘Arcane World of Bonds is Guide and Beacon to a Populist
President’, Wall Street Journal, 25 February 1993, p. A1.
2 Raymond
Goldsmith, Premodern Financial Systems (Cambridge, 1987), pp.
157ff., 164-9.
3 See M.
Veseth, Mountains of Debt: Crisis and Change in Renaissance Florence,
Victorian Britain and Postwar America (New York / Oxford, 1990).
4 John H. Munro,
‘The Origins of the Modern Financial Revolution: Responses to Impediments from
Church and State in Western Europe, 1200-1600’, University of Toronto Working
Paper, 2 (6 July 2001), p. 7.
5 James
Macdonald, A Free Nation Deep in Debt: The Financial Roots of Democracy(New
York, 2003), pp. 81ff.
6 Jean-Claude
Hocquet, ‘City-State and Market Economy’, in Richard Bonney (ed.), Economic
Systems and State Finance (Oxford, 1995), pp. 87-91.
7 Jean-Claude
Hocquet, ‘Venice’, in Richard Bonney (ed.), The Rise of the Fiscal
State in Europe, c. 1200-1815 (Oxford, 1999), p. 395.
8 FredericC.Lane,Venice:AMaritimeRepublic(Baltimore,1973),p.323.
9 Idem,
‘Venetian Bankers, 1496-1533: A Study in the Early Stages of Deposit
Banking’, Journal of Political Economy, 45, 2 (April 1937), pp.
197f.
10 Munro, ‘Origins
of the Modern Financial Revolution’, pp. 15f.
11 Martin Körner,
‘Public Credit’, in Richard Bonney (ed.), Economic Systems and State
Finance (Oxford, 1995), pp. 520f., 524f. See also Juan Gelabert,
‘Castile, 1504-1808’, in Richard Bonney (ed.), The Rise of the Fiscal
State in Europe, c. 1200-1815(Oxford, 1999), pp. 208ff.
12 Marjolein ’t
Hart, ‘The United Provinces 1579-1806’, in Richard Bonney (ed.), The
Rise of the Fiscal State in Europe, c. 1200-1815 (Oxford, 1999), pp.
311ff.
13 Douglass C. North
and Barry R. Weingast, ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of
Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England’, Journal
of Economic History, 49, 4 (1989), pp. 803-32. The classic account of
Britain’s financial revolution is P. G. M. Dickson, The Financial
Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit, 1688-1756 (London,
1967).
14 The best account
of the financial crisis of the ancien régime is J. F.
Bosher, French Finances, 1770-1795 (Cambridge, 1970).
15 Larry Neal, The
Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of
Reason (Cambridge, 1990).
16 Hansard,
New Series, vol. XVIII, pp. 540-43.
17 For a detailed
account, see Niall Ferguson, The World’s Banker: The History of the
House of Rothschild (London, 1998). See also Herbert H.
Kaplan, Nathan Mayer Rothschild and the Creation of a Dynasty: The Critical
Years, 1806-1816 (Stanford, 2006).
18 Rothschild
Archive, London, XI/109, Nathan Rothschild to his brothers Amschel, Carl and
James, 2 January 1816.
19 Rothschild
Archive, London, XI/109/2/2/156, Salomon, Paris, to Nathan, London, 29 October
1815.
20 See Lord [Victor]
Rothschild, The Shadow of a Great Man (London, 1982).
21 Philip
Ziegler, The Sixth Great Power: Barings, 1762-1929 (London,
1988), pp. 94f.
22 Heinrich
Heine, Ludwig Börne - ein Denkschrift: Samtliche Schriften, vol. IV
(Munich, 1971), p. 27.
23 Heinrich Heine,
‘Lutetia’, in Sämtliche Schriften, vol. V (Munich, 1971), pp.
321ff., 353.
24 Anon., The
Hebrew Talisman (London 1840), pp. 28ff.
25 Henry
Iliowzi, ‘In the Pale’: Stories and Legends of the Russian Jews(Philadelphia,
1897).
26 Richard McGregor,
‘Chinese Buy into Conspiracy Theory’, Financial Times, 26 September
2007.
27 Marc Flandreau
and Juan H. Flores, ‘Bonds and Brands: Lessons from the 1820s’, Center for
Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper, 6420 (August 2007).
28 For a more
complete list of all the bond issues with which the Rothschilds were in any way
associated, see J. Ayer, A Century of Finance, 1804 to 1904: The London
House of Rothschild (London, 1904), pp. 14-42
29 On Amsterdam, see
James C. Riley, International Government Finance and the Amsterdam
Capital Market (Cambridge, 1980), pp. 119-94.
30 Niall Ferguson,
‘The first “Eurobonds”: The Rothschilds and the Financing of the Holy Alliance,
1818-1822’, in William N. Goetzmann and K. Geert Rouwenhorst (eds.), The
Origins of Value: The Financial Innovations that Created Modern Capital Markets (Oxford,
2005), pp. 311-23.
31 Johann Heinrich
Bender, Über den Verkehr mit Staatspapieren in seinen Hauptrichtungen .
. . Als Beylageheft zum Archiv für die Civilist[ische] Praxis, vol. VIII
(Heidelberg, 1825), pp. 6ff.
32 Heine, Ludwig
Börne, p. 28.
33 Alfred
Rubens, Anglo-Jewish Portraits (London, 1935), p. 299.
34 The Times,
15 January 1821.
35 Bertrand
Gille, Histoire de la Maison Rothschild, vol. I: Des
origines à 1848(Geneva, 1965), p. 487.
36 Richard
Hofstadter, The Age of Reform from Bryan to F.D.R. (London,
1962), pp. 75ff.
37 Hermann Fürst
Pückler, Briefe eines Verstorbenen, ed. Heinz Ohff (Kupfergraben,
1986), p. 7.
38 J. A.
Hobson, Imperialism: A Study (London, 1902), Part I, ch. 4.
39 See e.g. Douglas
B. Ball, Financial Failure and Confederate Defeat (Urbana,
1991).
40 Irving
Katz, August Belmont: A Political Biography (New York, 1968),
esp. pp. 96-9.
41 S. Diamond
(ed.), A Casual View of America: The Home Letters of Salomon de
Rothschild, 1859-1861 (London, 1962).
42 See Rudolf Glanz,
‘The Rothschild Legend in America’, Jewish Social Studies, 19
(1957), pp. 3-28.
43 Marc D.
Weidenmier, ‘The Market for Confederate Cotton Bonds’, Explorations in
Economic History, 37 (2000), pp. 76-97. See also idem, ‘Turning
Points in the U.S. Civil War: Views from the Grayback Market’, Southern
Economic Journal, 68, 4 (2002), pp. 875-90.
44 See W. O.
Henderson, The Lancashire Cotton Famine: 1861-1865 (Manchester,
1934); Thomas Ellison, The Cotton Trade of Great Britain (New
York, 1968 [1886]).
45 Marc D. Weidenmier,
‘Comrades in Bonds: The Subsidized Sale of Confederate War Debt to British
Leaders’, Claremont McKenna College Working Paper (February 2003).
46 Richard
Roberts, Schroders: Merchants and Bankers (Basingstoke, 1992),
pp. 66f.
47 Richard C. K.
Burdekin and Marc D. Weidenmier, ‘Inflation is Always and Everywhere a Monetary
Phenomenon: Richmond vs. Houston in 1864’, American Economic Review,
91, 5 (December 2001), pp. 1621-30.
48 Richard Burdekin
and Marc Weidenmier, ‘Suppressing Asset Price Inflation: The Confederate
Experience, 1861-1865’, Economic Inquiry, 41, 3 (July 2003),
420-32. Cf. Eugene M. Lerner, ‘Money, Prices and Wages in the Confederacy,
1861-65’, Journal of Political Economy, 63, 1 (February 1955), pp.
20-40.
49 Frank Griffith
Dawson, The First Latin American Debt Crisis (London, 1990).
50 Kris James
Mitchener and Marc Weidenmier, ‘Supersanctions and Sovereign Debt Repayment’,
NBER Working Paper 11472 (2005).
51 Niall Ferguson
and Moritz Schularick, ‘The Empire Effect: The Determinants of Country Risk in
the First Age of Globalization, 1880- 1913’, Journal of Economic
History, 66, 2 (June 2006), pp. 283-312.
52 Kris James
Mitchener and Marc Weidenmier, ‘Empire, Public Goods, and the Roosevelt
Corollary’, Journal of Economic History, 65 (2005), pp. 658-92.
53 William
Cobbett, Rural Rides (London, 1985 [1830]), p. 117.
54 Ibid., pp. 34,
53.
55 M. de
Cecco, Money and Empire: The International Gold Standard, 1890-1914(Oxford,
1973).
56 Theo Balderston,
‘War Finance and Inflation in Britain and Germany, 1914-1918’, Economic
History Review, 42, 2 (May 1989), pp. 222- 44.
57 Calculated from
B. R. Mitchell, International Historical Statistics: Europe, 1750-1993 (London,
1998), pp. 358ff.
58 Jay Winter and
Jean-Louis Robert (eds.), Capital Cities at War: Paris, London, Berlin
1914-1919, Studies in the Social and Cultural History of Modern Warfare,
No. 2 (Cambridge, 1997), p. 259.
59 Gerald D.
Feldman, The Great Disorder: Politics, Economy and Society in the
German Inflation, 1914-1924 (Oxford / New York, 1997), pp. 211-54.
60 Elias
Canetti, Crowds and Power (New York, 1988), p. 186.
61 John Maynard
Keynes, A Tract on Monetary Reform, reprinted in Collected
Writings, vol. IV (Cambridge, 1971), pp. 3, 29, 36.
62 John Maynard
Keynes, The Economic Consequences of the Peace (London, 1919),
pp. 220-33.
63 Frank Whitson
Fetter, ‘Lenin, Keynes and Inflation’, Economica, 44, 173 (February
1977), p. 78.
64 William C. Smith,
‘Democracy, Distributional Conflicts and Macroeconomic Policymaking in
Argentina, 1983-89’, Journal of Inter-american Studies and World
Affairs, 32, 2 (Summer 1990), pp. 1- 42. Cf. Rafael Di Tella and Ingrid
Vogel, ‘The Argentine Paradox: Economic Growth and Populist Tradition’, Harvard
Business School Case 9-702-001 (2001).
65 Jorge Luis
Borges, ‘The Garden of Forking Paths’, in idem, Labyrinths:
Selected Stories and Other Writings, ed. Donald A. Yates and James E. Irby
(Harmondsworth, 1970), pp. 50ff.
66 Ferguson, World’s
Banker, ch. 27.
67 Further details
in Gerardo della Paolera and Alan M. Taylor, Straining at the Anchor:
The Argentine Currency Board and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability,
1880-1935 (Chicago, 2001).
68 ‘A Victory by
Default’, Economist, 3 March 2005.
69 For a recent
discussion of the issue, see Michael Tomz, Reputation and International
Cooperation: Sovereign Debt across Three Centuries (Princeton, 2007).
70 On the Great
Inflation, see Fabrice Collard and Harris Dellas, ‘The Great Inflation of the
1970s’, Working Paper (1 October 2003); Edward Nelson, ‘The Great Inflation of
the Seventies: What Really Happened?’, Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Working
Paper, 2004- 001 (January 2004); Allan H. Meltzer, ‘Origins of the Great
Inflation’, Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review, Part 2 (March
/ April 2005), pp. 145-75.
71 The eleven
markets are Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Hong Kong, Ireland, Japan,
Netherlands, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States. See Watson
Wyatt, ‘Global Pension Fund Assets Rise and Fall’: http://www.watsonwyatt.com/news/press. asp?ID=18579.
72 CNN, 9 July 2000.
73 Testimony of
Chairman Alan Greenspan, Federal Reserve Board’s semi-annual Monetary Policy
Report to the Congress, before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban
Affairs, US Senate, 16 February 2005.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario